[1] Samuelson P A. Proof that properly anticipated prices fluctuate randomly[J]. Industrial Management Review, 1965, 6(2): 41-49. [2] Grossman S J. The existence of futures markets, noisy rational expectations and informational externalities[J]. The Review of Economic Studies, 1977, 44(3): 431-449. [3] Keynes J M. Some aspects of commodity markets[J]. Manchester Guardian Commercial: European Reconstruction Series, 1923, 13: 784-786. [4] Hicks J R. Value and Capital:An inquiry into some fundamental principles of economic theory[M]. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1939. [5] Hong H, Yogo M. What does futures market interest tell us about the macroeconomy and asset prices?[J]. } of Financial Economics, 2012, 105(3): 473-490. [6] Mankiw N G, Zeldes S P. The consumption of stockholders and nonstockholders[J]. Journal of Financial Economics, 1991, 29(1): 97-112. [7] Heaton J, Lucas D. Stock prices and fundamentals[J]. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 1999, 14: 213-242. [8] Harrison H, Kubik J D, Stein J C. Social interaction and stock-market participation[J]. The Journal of Finance, 2004, 59(1): 137-163. [9] Piotroski J D, Roulstone B T. The influence of analysts, institutional investors, and insiders on the incorporation of market, industry, and firm-specific information into stock prices[J]. The Accounting Review, 2004, 79(4): 1119-1151. [10] Mankiw N G, Reis R. Sticky information versus sticky prices: a proposal to replace the new keynesian phillips curve[J]. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2002, 117(4): 1295-1328. [11] Gourinchas P, Tornell A. Exchange rate puzzles and distorted beliefs[J]. Journal of International Economics, 2004, 64(2): 303-333. [12] Hong H, Stein J C. A unified theory of underreaction, momentum trading, and overreaction in asset markets[J]. The Journal of Finance, 1999, 54(6): 2143-2184. [13] Fischer S. Long-term contracts, rational expectations, and the optimal money supply rule[J]. Journal of Political Economy, 1977, 85(1): 191-205. [14] Blanchard O, Watson M. Bubbles, rational expectations and financial markets[J]. NBER Working Paper, 1983. [15] Kodres L E, Pritsker M. A rational expectations model of financial contagion[J]. The Journal of Finance, 2002, 57(2): 769-799. [16] Long J B D, Shleifer A, Summers L H, et al. Noise trader risk in financial markets[J]. Journal of Political Economy, 1990, 98(4): 703-738. [17] Shleifer A. Do demand curves for stocks slope down?[J]. The Journal of Finance, 1986, 41(3): 579-590. [18] Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC). Commitments of traders reports. 2008. http://www.cftc.gov/MarketReports/CommitmentsofTraders/index.htm [19] Grossman S J, Stiglitz J E. Information and competitive price systems[J]. The American Economic Review, 1976, 66(2): 246-253. [20] Easley D, Kiefer N M, O’Hara M, et al. Liquidity, Information, and infrequently traded stocks[J]. The Journal of Finance, 1996, 51(4): 1405-1436. [22] Campbell J Y, Cochrane J H. By force of habit: a consumption-based explanation of aggregate stock market behavior[J]. Journal of Political Economy, 1999, 107(2): 205-251. [23] Li G. Time-varying risk aversion and asset prices[J]. Journal of Banking & Finance, 2007, 31(1): 243-257. |